Exploring the Nexus Between Inclusive Growth and Institutional Quality


Applied Economics Research Centre, University of Karachi, Pakistan

Abstract

This study conducts an empirical investigation to identify the relationship between institutional quality and inclusive growth. It examines the existing situation of inclusive growth and institutional quality in 86 countries. It further constructs indices of inclusive growth using social welfare function and institutional quality by applying the principal component methodology to worldwide governance indicators. The fixed effect results suggest that Institutional quality is a significant driver for achieving growth inclusiveness. A deep underpinning of the institutional variable indicates that inclusive growth is positively affected by economic and political institution quality. In contrast, the effect of legal institutions was found insignificant. Furthermore, a cross-country evaluation of inclusive growth presented a few thoughtful insights, such as; in low-income and lower-income economies, inclusive growth can be achieved by increasing the overall opportunities. Whereas middle and high-income economies need to enhance the equity prospects of opportunities to attain growth inclusiveness. By highlighting the role of institutional quality, this study contributes to the existing literature on growth inclusiveness. It suggests that improved quality of institutions, the rule of law, reduced corruption, regulatory quality, securing property rights, and effective governance can extend the opportunities to the unprivileged segment of the society, ensuring long-term growth.

Keywords

institutional quality, inclusive growth, equity, social welfare function, principal component methodology

Introduction

The world has recently observed significant improvement in the living standard, accompanied by an increasing level of inequality, especially in emerging economies. Whereas few developed economies are also watching the episodes of rising inequality. It is a fact that economic growth is not meeting the ends of people belonging to lower-income segments of society. If we look at the elephant curve Figure 3, the distribution of benefits produced due to economic growth is quite discriminatory. Across the globe bottom, 50% of the population enjoys only 12 percent of the total growth, whereas; the top captures more than 1/4th of the total growth benefits. Despite enjoying higher growth rates, few of the world’s biggest economies sit at the bottom on the map of equitable distribution of opportunities (Alvaredo, Chancel, Piketty, Saez, & Zucman, 2018; Dollar & Kraay, 2003; Eldomiaty, Qassemi, Mabrouk, & Abdelghany, 2015).

In the last few decades, economic growth worldwide remained exemplary, yet the inequality trend kept showing an upward movement, raising many questions recently.In their research paper,Ali and Son (2007) tried to answer this question through the concept of inclusive growth.Inclusive growth utilizes the unemployed segment of the labour force by providing employment opportunities; it helps them move out of extreme poverty and improve productive employment (Ianchovichina & Lundström, 2009). Every part of society can benefit from the resulting economic growth. Hence, inclusiveness, a multidimensional concept, concentrates on raising living standards and improved well-being and questions whether this material well-being is evenly shared among different social groups.

Considering its long-term implication, inclusive growth has gasped so much attention since its emergence, and several policies have been designed and implemented. Among those policies, most of them have been used in the past. The policies include; attracting foreign direct investment, fiscal expansion, small-scale investments, infrastructural improvements, and ICT and technological advancement (Aoyagi & Ganelli, 2015). Yet the results remained contradictory as these policies remained effective for promoting growth only in a few countries. At the same time, similar policies helped a few economies to achieve the twin objective of fulfilling growth with a reduced level of inequality (Doumbia, 2019). A reliable explanation for such variation was presented by other authors in previous studies (Acemoglu & Robinson, 2008; Acemoglu & Robinson, 2010; Acemoglu, Johnson, & Robinson, 2001). The central argument of their research was the differences in prosperity across countries are due to differences in institutions. They argued that differences in outcomes of any policy are due to variations in choices of economic and political institutions. Similarly, according to Ali et al. (2007), the core requirement to achieve inclusive growth is introducing institutional and governance reform to restructure policies, address market failures, and ensure a growth process. Everyone can play a role and avail themselves of the opportunities.

Due to its significance, a decent amount of research work in the area of inclusive growth has already been done (Adedeji, Du, & Opoku-Afari, 2013; Ali & Zhuang, 2007; Anand, Mishra, & Peiris, 2013; Ianchovichina & Gable, 2012), yet the research remained limited to its measurement, identification of determinants, and policies mainly. Furthermore, the relationship between institutional quality and inclusive growth remained limited to theoretical research. Hence, this study contributes to the existing set of knowledge by conducting an empirical investigation of the association between inclusive growth and institutional quality.

Literature Review

The idea of institutional role came into highlight after World War I when the importance of institutions, policy-making, and governments’ role in the economy emerged. Veblen the founder of institutionalism in his famous “Veblenian dichotomy,” highlighted the role of institutions in different economic activities and negated the role of invisible hands in Large — Scale manufacturing, corporate finance, and salesmanship (Hodgson, 2012). The revival of new classical economics by introducing the role of the institution in the economy created the base of New Institutional Economics (NIE). Later, the pioneer of new institutional economics (Lindert, Williamson, Lindert, & Williamson, 1985; North & Thomas, 1973; North, 1991) argued that economic growth and institutions complement each other, but the literature remained limited to growth implications of institutional quality till 1997.

At the start of the 21st century, the role of institutions started being investigated for economic growth, poverty, inequality, provision of public service, and economic development (Acemoglu et al., 2008; Alexiou, Tsaliki, & Osman, 2014; Bluhm & Szirmai, 2011; Chong & Gradstein, 2007; Sonin, 2003; Zhuang & Ali, 2010). Similarly, Josifidis, Supić, and Beker-Pucar (2017), while analyzing the distributional inequality of income in advanced economies, concluded that variation in institutional quality creates differences in the interests of the people holding the higher positions in an economy which deteriorates income distribution.

Ali et al. (2007) first highlighted the role of institutions in achieving inclusive growth. While defining the key measures to promote growth inclusiveness in their study, they suggested that institutions play a prerequisite role in making any policy effective. They further argued that the roles of institutions and governance need to be embedded to obtain inclusive growth outcomes. Inclusive growth requires the participation of all individuals belonging to any income class, even the most marginalized segment of the society, not only in the growth process but also in the decision-making process. That inclusion of institutions will enable the designed policies to be favourable towards the unprivileged segment and achieve higher growth objectives. Considering the importance of institutional quality for achieving inclusive growth, the study conducts a cross-country investigation using the fixed-effect method. The study initially constructs and calculates an index for inclusive growth and institutional quality to fulfill the objectives.

The construction of an inclusive growth index requires integrating the concept of growth and equity in a suitable measure. The most commonly used approach by the research over the past few years has been the opportunity/equity index based on the utilitarian social opportunity function. This function depends on the availability of opportunities and distribution of those opportunities, growth is determined to be inclusive if it increases the overall opportunity function. Additionally, this function gives higher weight to the opportunities available to poor people; another attribute of this type of analysis is that it enables us to examine the change in the distribution of opportunities over time (Adedeji et al., 2013; Ali et al., 2007; Anand et al., 2013). Institutional quality is a broad concept that integrates several aspects such as the government’s efficiency in planning and implementing, freedom of expression and doing business, accountability, corruption control, and regulatory quality. To capture all these social, political, economic, and legal aspects, the most commonly used data in the recent literature on institutions are found to be based on worldwide governance indicators (WGI), introduced by (Kraay, Zoido-Lobaton, & Kaufmann, 1999).

The WGI data constitutes six broad dimensions namely; voice and accountability, government effectiveness, control of corruption, regulatory quality, rule of law, and political stability and violence. Right after its introduction, it became the most widely used data as a proxy for institutional quality (Eldomiaty et al., 2015; Iheonu, Ihedimma, & Onwuanaku, 2017; Nawaz, Iqbal, & Khan, 2014; Tran, Cameron, & Poot, 2017; Zhuang et al., 2010). There are several reasons to use this data set such as; the data covering political and non-political aspects of institutions, it includes the perception of a wide range of stakeholders 1 , and its empirical usability. Based on this extensive significance we will also use the WGI dataset in order to develop the institutional quality index.

Methodology

Measuring Inclusive Growth

To study the dual objective of efficiency and equity under one umbrella, the idea of generalized concentration curve is most commonly used, introduced initially by Ali et al. (2007). According to this, the population is arranged in ascending order in accordance with the opportunity they attain. Let   Y - i be the average opportunity available to bottom ith percentile where i ranges from 0 to 100 and Y - is the mean of that opportunity. Figure 1 depicts the same level of average opportunities Y - with a different pattern of distribution Y - i , here we can see that a higher level of social mobility and inclusive growth is dependent on (i) if the curve moves up at all points (growth), (ii) if the distribution of the opportunity changes (equity) 2 .

https://typeset-prod-media-server.s3.amazonaws.com/article_uploads/412ebe3d-c61c-412c-8427-8daa81b72a30/image/45b90845-c276-4aff-8838-2f9cc24c9d9f-ufig1.png
Figure 1: Social Mobility Curve

By calculating the area under the social mobility curve, we can develop social opportunity index that is;

Y * = 0 100 Y - i   d i

The above equation presents the following points.

1. Y ¯ will be equal to Y ¯ * in a completely equitable society.

2. If Y ¯ * is lower than Y ¯ the distribution of income will be inequitable.

3. A higher Y ¯ * depicts the higher level of income across all segments.

Here, Y ¯ shows on average availability of opportunities in a society Y ¯ * shows the average opportunities available at each income quintile; hence, the difference between Y ¯ * and Y ¯ shows an unequal distribution of opportunities. Based on thisAli et al. (2007) proposed the Income Equity index (IEI),

ω i = Y ¯ * Y ¯

In a completely equitable society, value of IEI will be equal to one.

Y ¯ * = ω   * Y ¯

Equation 2.b defines that inclusive growth depends on average income and its distributional equity measured by the Income Equity index (IEI). This suggests that inclusive growth can be achieved by increasing Y ¯ or by increasing the value of the equity index ( ω i   )

D y ¯ * = ω i * d y ¯ + d ω i * y ¯

Here, d y ¯ * represents the change in the degree of growth inclusiveness. This suggests that growth is more inclusive if d y - * > 0 . This increase in d y - * can be achieved by adopting any of these two policy measures i) growth-oriented policies that increase the average income ( d y - ) ii) policies that make the distribution of the resources or opportunities more equitable ( d ω i   ) (Klasen, 2010).

Following more interpretations can be drawn from equation (iii)

1- d y - >   0 and d ω > 0 — growth is unambiguously inclusive

2- d y - <   0 and d ω < 0 — growth is unambiguously non-inclusive

3- d y ¯ > 0 and d ω <   0 — can be inclusive (if the percentage change in average opportunities is greater than the percentage change in ω )

4- d y - <   0 and d ω < 0 — can be inclusive if the percentage change in ω is greater than the percentage change in average opportunities.

The above discussion helped us to calculate our inclusive growth variable. 3 To calculate, we took GDP per capita data as the average opportunity available in the society ( Y ¯ ) , for ( Y ¯ * ) we averaged income share held at different income quintiles. 4

Measuring Institutional Quality Index

To calculate the institutional quality index, we applied Principal Component Analysis (PCA) on all six WGI indicators (government effectiveness, voice and accountability, regulatory quality, control of corruption, rule of law and political stability and violence) introduced by Kaufmann and Kraay (1999). PCA uses an orthogonal transformation to convert a large number of correlated variables to a smaller number of uncorrelated variables called principal components. PCA also helps to mitigate bias which any objective weight assigning can create, as it assigns the weights for each indicator from its data.

Regression framework for IG and IQI

We have used the following regression to determine the role of institutional quality in growth inclusiveness.

Y * i , t - Y * i , t - 1 = α i t + β 0 I Q I i t + β 1 X i t + ε i t

In the above equation Y* i, t -Y* i, t-1 is the log difference of Y ¯ * ; IQI is the institutional quality index, measured using WGI indicators, X i t is the set of control variables which includes domestic credit to the private sector, inflation, merchandise trade statistics as a percentage of GDP, age dependency ratio, Government’s Final consumption expenditure, and fixed investment as a percentage of GDP, while ε i t is the error term.

To analyze which type of institutional quality mostly describes the variation in growth inclusiveness, we have regressed Inclusive growth on Political, economic, and legal quality of institutions from 1996 to 2010 (unbalanced panel) along with the same vector of control variable.

Y * i , t - Y * i , t - 1 = α i t + β 0 I Q I P o l i t i c a l   i t + β 1 X i t + ε i t
Y * i , t - Y * i , t - 1 = α i t + β 0 I Q I E c o n o m i c   i t + β 1 X i t + ε i t
Y * i , t - Y * i , t - 1 = = α i t + β 0 I Q I L e g a l   i t + β 1 X i t + ε i t

Data Sources

The study uses the unbalanced panel data for 86 countries from 1996 to 2015 with few gaps in the initial six years. The data for two key variables (Inclusive growth and Institutional quality) has been constructed by using different methods suggested by the literature as discussed in the previous section. For constructing Inclusive growth, we have used data of Per capita Income and Income distribution held at each 20% (to assess distributional pattern) from the database of World Bank. For the construction of the Institutional quality index, we utilized WGI data sets (1996-2015), whereas to establish a deep understanding of institutional quality data for different kinds of institutional quality (economic, political and legal) has been obtained fromKunčič (2014) from 1990 to 2010. The selection of time period and the country was mostly dictated by the availability of data for our two key variables. The data of the control variable is taken from several international organizations which include World Trade Organization, World Bank National Accounts database, International financial statistics, International Monetary Fund and United Nations’ population division data. The list of control variables includes; FDI, Gross fixed capital formation (% of GDP) as a proxy for fixed investment and general government final consumption expenditure (% of GDP), inflation measured by consumer price index and domestic credit to private sector and age dependency ratio.

Assessing Growth Inclusiveness and Institutional Quality

Assessing Inclusive Growth

This section provides the empirical assessment of the results obtained by using the concept of the social opportunity curve. As per our earlier discussion, an increase in inclusive growth can be achieved by increasing ( Y ¯ * ) which depends on two factors; an Increasing average level of overall opportunities ( Y ¯ ) and increasing the equity index of opportunities ( ω ) For conducting an assessment we have calculated change in inclusive growth d y ¯ * , change in per-capita income d y ¯ and change in equity index of income ( d ω i   ) .

A few of the major findings are as follows:

1- Few of the world’s major economies despite having higher standing on the growth map are performing quite unsatisfactorily in terms of equity surprisingly the United States managed to be in that list. From 2004 to 2016 USA’s equity growth index has declined by 1.53%. Australia with a small increase in overall opportunities (1.62%) and lower equity index (-0.70%), South Africa’s decline in growth of Equity index of income by 4.32%, and Germany’s by 2.92% brought them in the list of lower-performing economies in terms of inclusive growth.

2- Other countries such as countries like Ethiopia, Zambia, Tajikistan, Lao PDR, Vietnam, Bosnia, and Herzegovina, and Magnolia; despite showing negative growth in terms of equity, successfully performed quite well in terms of inclusive growth which is shown by higher growth in GDP Per capita. This suggests that inclusive growth is achieved by increasing the overall opportunity whereas lower attention has been paid to the equity side of the growth.

3- Among the list of countries with higher inclusive growth very few of the high-income economies successfully secured any position.

https://typeset-prod-media-server.s3.amazonaws.com/article_uploads/cf98a60d-8460-4a0e-b0e0-2334decf7483/image/f3415124-bde8-490c-a2e1-75029d79741c-utable-1.png
Figure 2: Assessing Inclusive Growth around the Globe (Source: Authors’ calculation)

These findings helped us to conclude that countries with a low level of an initial endowment of resources should prioritize increasing the overall resource availability rather than the distributional pattern. Secondly, countries that already have achieved a substantial rate of economic growth or made an efficient number of resources available on average to their people need to start considering the pattern of the distribution more than compared to pace.

The results suggest that neither the same level of growth nor the higher pace of growth in the two countries ensures a similar level of growth inclusiveness. As the distributional heterogeneity depends on the economy’s policy making. Additionally, there are strong instances in which growth is achieved without compromising equity.

Assessing Institutional Quality

Based on the discussed methodology in the above section, we implied PCM, to identify principal components, which account for most of the variation in the data. All the three criteria discussed [See Appendix B 2] suggest selecting only the first principal component. The first principal component explains 88.29% of the variation in the data. Later we transformed the original WGI data into a single composite institutional index by using the following method.

P C 1 = X * L
I Q I = P C 1 / P C 1   ( M a x ) * 100

Equation 8 shows that PC1 is obtained by multiplying data with factor loading later it is rescaled by dividing with the largest element to develop the composite index for institutional quality.

The resulting index from the above empirical implication brought several conclusions discussed as under:

1- The majority of the high-income economies 5 stood at a higher rank on the institutional quality index. Such as the United Kingdom, Finland, Sweden, Ireland, Netherlands, Australia, Switzerland, Denmark, Canada, Germany, Estonia, Luxembourg, Norway, Austria, Chile, Belgium, Lithuania, Iceland, Israel, and United States ranked among the top 20 on our IQI ranking.

2- Despite the top ranks being held by high-income countries yet their performance over almost two decades remained quite stagnant or either deteriorated. Countries like Italy, Greece, Slovenia, Uruguay, Spain, Cyprus, Austria, United Kingdom, Luxemburg, Hungary, and Denmark have shown negative growth in the IQI index while computing the change over the periods of 1996 to 2015.

3- The bottom 20 positions were majorly held by lower middle income (Nicaragua, Honduras, Tunisia, Zambia, Vietnam, Côte d’Ivoire, Ukraine, Pakistan, Iran, Islamic Rep., Argentina, Egypt, Arab Rep. Bolivia & Bangladesh) and low-income countries (Niger, Madagascar & Guinea) with an exception of Belarus, Ethiopia, Ecuador, Venezuela and RB Russian Federation belonging to the upper-middle-income country.

4- Compared to others few lower-middle-income economies and low-income economies have shown positive improvements such as Ethiopia (27.01%), Niger (18.94%), El-Salvador (18.48%), Honduras (18.06%), Madagascar (10.07%), and Vietnam (7.06%) etc.

Table 1: Analyzing Institutional Quality Index

Country

Rank

CL

Avg. IQI

Change

Country

Rank

CL

Avg..IQI

Change

United Kingdom

1

HI

1.64759

-3.936

Panama

44

UMI

-0.3240

-10.171

Finland

2

HI

1.63639

7.533

Thailand

45

UMI

-0.0996

9.74737

Sweden

3

HI

1.61399

13.814

South Africa

46

UMI

-0.1108

-8.5119

Ireland

4

HI

1.61399

8.137

Turkey

47

UMI

-0.122

7.0845

Netherland

5

HI

1.59159

-0.966

Armenia

48

LMI

-0.1556

25.7476

Australia

6

HI

1.58039

11.445

El Salvador

49

LMI

-0.2004

18.4869

Switzerland

7

HI

1.52439

4.664

Albania

50

UMI

-0.2116

36.0734

Denmark

8

HI

1.51319

-1.226

Serbia

51

UMI

-0.2452

55.7102

Canada

9

HI

1.50199

6.069

Jamaica

52

UMI

-0.3012

-3.6006

Germany

10

HI

1.50199

6.350

Jordan

53

UMI

-0.3348

2.58668

Estonia

11

HI

1.44599

12.148

Kazakhstan

54

UMI

-0.458

15.2315

Luxemburg

12

HI

1.43479

-2.463

Dom. Republic

55

UMI

-0.4692

9.18045

Norway

13

HI

1.37879

2.088

Philippines

56

LMI

-0.4692

-2.5867

Austria

14

HI

1.14359

-6.566

Sri Lanka

57

LMI

-0.4804

-4.6618

Chile

15

HI

1.08759

-4.948

Moldova

58

LMI

-0.5028

-6.00E05

Belgium

16

HI

1.02039

2.279

Senegal

59

LI

-0.6036

-1.3827

Lithuania

17

HI

1.00919

5.917

Brazil

60

UMI

-0.6372

-18.849

Iceland

18

HI

0.99799

0.563

Azerbaijan

61

UMI

-0.7044

86.3948

Israel

19

HI

0.99799

5.621

Uganda

62

LI

-0.7156

-10.134

United States

20

HI

0.98679

-8.484

Paraguay

63

UMI

-0.7268

12.1574

Malta

21

HI

0.88599

6.116

Mongolia

64

LMI

-0.8164

-8.4523

France

22

HI

0.84119

2.388

Burkina Faso

65

LI

-0.8388

-3.5007

Czech Republic

23

HI

0.80758

0.890

Nicaragua

66

LMI

-0.8612

2.68873

Latvia

24

HI

0.79638

5.938

Honduras

67

LMI

-0.8724

18.0169

Cyprus

25

HI

0.76279

-5.618

Tunisia

68

LMI

-0.8836

-22.545

Poland

26

HI

0.69558

9.272

Zambia

69

LMI

-0.9172

2.19835

Portugal

27

HI

0.65079

-7.387

Vietnam

70

LMI

-0.962

7.06048

Spain

28

HI

0.48278

-10.633

Cote Di Voire

71

LMI

-0.9844

-5.2643

Slovak Republic

29

HI

0.46038

4.040

Russ. Federation

72

UMI

-1.0068

-4.8138

Hungary

30

HI

0.43798

-2.540

Ukraine

73

LMI

-1.0852

-9.0445

Malaysia

31

UMI

0.41558

0.974

Pakistan

74

LMI

-1.13

-6.7054

Italy

32

HI

0.39318

-4.114

Niger

75

LI

-1.242

18.9449

Slovenia

33

HI

0.28118

-13.570

Madagascar

76

LI

-1.2868

10.0747

Romania

34

UMI

0.24758

24.467

Egypt

77

LMI

-1.3652

-35.117

Bulgaria

35

UMI

0.20278

34.912

Guinea

78

LI

-1.3988

-2.0553

Costa Rica

36

UMI

0.16918

-0.701

Bolivia

79

LMI

-1.4212

-38.702

Peru

37

UMI

0.12438

0.000

Bangladesh

80

LMI

-1.4324

2.19046

Colombia

38

UMI

0.10198

26.488

Argentina

81

UMI

-1.4436

-50.716

Botswana

39

UMI

0.06838

-7.119

Belarus

82

UMI

-1.5332

8.26717

Uruguay

40

HI

0.04598

-13.377

Ethiopia

83

LI

-1.578

27.0108

Greece

41

HI

0.03478

-4.578

Ecuador

84

UMI

-1.7236

-42.722

Croatia

42

HI

-0.0212

24.887

Iran

85

LMI

-1.8916

12.5056

Mexico

43

UMI

-0.0212

9.466

Venezuela

86

UMI

-2.53

-78.91

Average value of IQI is taken to assign ranks to the countries whereas change shows the change in the value of IQI over the period of 1996 to 2015. Here, HI* High Income Economies; UMI* Upper middle-income economies; LMI* Lower Middle-Income Economies; LI* Lower Income Economies

Institutional Quality and Inclusive Growth Nexus

To identify the role of institutional quality in promoting inclusive growth, the study utilized unbalanced panel data of 86 countries from 1996 to 2015. In Table 2 Column 1 presents the result of fixed effect estimates corrected for heteroscedasticity. The robust results were obtained due to the presence of heteroscedasticity. The results of the Modified Wald test for group-wise heteroscedasticity reflect the presence of heteroscedasticity (Engle, 1984) (Appendix C 3). The test presented the evidence against our null hypothesis of homoscedasticity (or constant variance) hence, the robust results for fixed effect were obtained which automatically corrects standard errors for heteroskedasticity. For the selection of an appropriate panel data model for our objective, we have applied the Hausman specification test to choose between FE and RE (Hausman, 1978). The results obtained from the Hausman test suggested FE technique is more appropriate. The basic null hypothesis for Hausman’s preferred model is random effect against the alternative hypothesis of fixed effect. The Chi square probability of the Hausman test is less than 0.05 hence fixed effect coefficients and results are more appropriate for our analytical study Appendix C 3.

Our results for control variables suggest that inflation, government final consumption and age dependency ratio have a negative and significant effect on inclusive growth. This suggests that inflation by reducing the real purchasing power further deprives the masses of accessing certain resources hence reducing the inclusivity while; a higher dependency ratio itself reflects the exclusion of a high number of individuals from the growth process (Anand et al., 2013) Another set of control variables by showing significant positive association such as trade openness, financial deepening, and fixed investment suggests that they have helped countries achieve growth inclusiveness. However, FDI does not appear to have any positive and significant association. Our key variable Institutional quality has shown a significant and positive association with inclusive growth. As the institutional quality variable is calculated by implying PCM on WGI indicators which predicts the complete social, economic, political, and legal aspects of institutional quality hence, our variable depicts the relationships among the overall quality of institutions without being specific to any particular type of institution or neglecting any of them and inclusive growth. Column 2 to 4 of Table 2 shows that economic and political institutions influence inclusive growth positively and significantly while legal institutions are found to have an insignificant negative association with growth inclusiveness. As average opportunities availability majorly relies on economic institutions, the difference in efficacy of economic institutions is translated by differences in political institutions. (Acemoglu et al., 2008). The results agree with the theoretical understanding ofAli et al. (2007) as they argued that the initial and first most requirement for inclusive growth is to take political and economic institutions on board to make result-oriented policies.

Table 2: Institutions and Inclusive Growth (Fixed effect estimates)

Variables

Institutional Quality Index

Legal

Institutions

Political

Institution

Economic

Institution

Institutional Quality

0.1721659***

-0.02674

0.2936572**

0.2670272***

0.0515492

0.1025598

0.1157987

0.0873898

Government Consumtipn (% GDP)

(0.0099607)*

(0.0107225)***

(0.0108314)***

(0.0110659)***

0.0054816

0.0028574

0.0028238

0.0028152

Fixed Investment (%GDP)

0.0015526***

0.0028532***

(0.0028067)***

0.0026958***

0.0003623

0.0002775

0.0002754

0.0002784

Financial Deepening

0.0005652**

(0.0004915)*

(0.0004863)*

(0.0005587)*

0.0002524

0.0002907

0.0002879

0.0002875

Trade openness

0.001674***

-0.0000132

-0.0000398

-0.000173

0.0004402

0.0003007

0.0002931

0.0002958

Inflation

(0.0008598)**

(0.0007802)**

(0.0006832)**

(0.0006376)**

0.0003396

0.000318

0.000314

0.0003139

Dependency Ratio

(0.0021337)**

(0.0047559)**

(0.0049474)***

(0.0050266)***

0.000922

0.001425

0.0014085

0.0014038

Foreign Direct Investment

-0.0000446

0.0000578

0.0000619

0.0000513

0.0000744

0.0001692

0.0001677

0.0001671

cons

0.3122526***

0.4724296***

0.4838885***

0.4920386***

0.1125186

0.0926141

0.0913076

0.0910788

No. of observation

733

455

455

455

No. of groups

81

79

79

79

R-squared

0.33

0.34

0.35

0.35

Note:(In column 1) Dependent variable inclusive growth is regressed on IQI (composite indicator for measuring institutional quality measured using WGI dataset) and number of control variables, Panel estimations with fixed effects (FE corrected for heteroskedasticity) estimated where ‘***”, ‘**’, ‘*’ denote significance at the 1, 5, or 10 percent level, respectively.

For columns 2 to 4 inclusive growth is regressed for the quality of different institutional arrangements (Economic, Legal and political). The period for column 1 1996 to 2015 whereas for column 2 to 4 1996 to 2010.

Dependent Variable: Growth in Y ¯ * (inclusive growth)

Discussion

The findings presented above have various implications for policymakers around the world. The resulted empirics brought some thoughtful insights. Countries with higher economic growth could be performing quite unsatisfactory in terms of equity. Theories suggest two major possibilities behind such results, Firstly, the growth policies are designed in such a way that their benefits are mainly being enjoyed by the individuals belonging to upper income segments of the society secondly the policies completely neglect the marginalized segments. Limiting the probability of accessing the opportunities, generated by the growth process, widens the gap among classes (Derviş & Qureshi, 2016; Keskin, 2017). The second observation was that few of the lower income economies performed quite well in terms of equity one of the justifications for such results are that lower income economies have lower level of initial inequality. Hence, as they progress the expansion of average opportunities contract the gap further among their marginalized and upper income segment ensuring growth inclusiveness. The above two observations made us to conclude that countries already enjoying substantial amount of economic growth needs to focus on the pattern more than compared to pace. Countries with lower level of initial endowment can achieve inclusiveness, through increasing the average opportunities. As discussed, inclusive growth can be achieved by designing policies that result in improved and equitable opportunities distribution. Policies that target economic inequalities and ensure better access to the existing and newly created economic opportunities can create an inclusive economic environment (K. & A., 2022). There are also several areas for further development, as the study limited itself to cover only one aspect of opportunity, which is an income opportunity. Nevertheless, the theory suggests that income itself defines access to several other opportunities. Yet, a detailed analysis of access to other opportunities such as health care and education can broaden the horizon.

Conclusion

The purpose of this study was twofold: first to assess the existing position of the countries on the inclusive growth map, and second to investigate the link between inclusive growth and institutional quality within the context of 86 countries around the world including the representation of countries from different income classification. The study is relevant to the current scenario of rising inequality within and across countries, especially for the policymakers who must balance this growth and inequality trade-off. The evidence shows that a higher quality of institutions helps in translating economic growth policies into inclusive growth-oriented. The result supports the main hypothesis of a positive association between institutional quality and inclusive growth around the world. Furthermore, by using the institutional quality dataset constructed by (Kunčič, 2014) for different institutional arrangements the study concludes that the quality of economic and political institutions matters most for inclusive growth. Looking forward, several issues need to be addressed first before implementing an inclusive growth policy such as infrastructural improvement, distributional equity, and institutional quality. The way economies react to policies differently stresses the need for improving the quality of institutions, to make any policy inclusive and growth-oriented. Furthermore, a tremendous amount of effort is required to link macroeconomic policies with inclusive growth instead of limiting them to growth only.